Skip to Content Skip to Footer
Optimizing Timing in Pay-What-You-Want Models [Expert Strategies]

Optimizing Timing in Pay-What-You-Want Models [Expert Strategies]

Raghabendra P. KC, Vincent Mak and Elie Ofek

Pay-what-you-want is a pricing mechanism where consumers can decide how much to pay for a product or service. Variations of this idea have been employed widely over the years. Public museums, such as New York’s Metropolitan Museum of Art, have long allowed nominally free entry but with requests for donations at entry and/or exit. Panera Bread in the U.S. and the British band Radiohead have both carried out pay-what-you-want arrangements in highly publicized campaigns. Public (public.com) offers brokerage services without a fixed commission rate and earns revenue from optional tipping. The Guardian newspaper website and Wikipedia have long upheld successful pay-what-you-want models: The Guardian received contributions from more than 1 million readers between 2016 and 2018, and the Wikimedia Foundation raised more than US$120 million in contributions in the fiscal year ending June 30, 2020.

Pay-what-you-want involves the consumer voluntarily paying the seller any (or no) amount of money in return for being unconditionally offered a product or service: an example of a social exchange. With the proliferation of business models based on social exchanges, where businesses refrain from charging fixed prices that might turn away customers who cannot afford them, the pay-what-you-want mechanism has become more prominent in recent years. However, the success of the pricing mechanism is not guaranteed. For example, Panera’s use of pay-what-you-want did not attain its desired results and was discontinued. Companies implementing pay-what-you-want pricing should carefully align factors that could psychologically affect payments.

In a new Journal of Marketing article, we study whether consumers’ payments differ depending on when they are asked to make their payment decision—before or after receiving the unconditionally offered product—and, if a difference exists, why it occurs and under what conditions. We propose that people pay different amounts depending on the timing of their payment decision, even when there is minimal change in uncertainty regarding the value of the product at different timings.

Advertisement

Timing Versus Value

Our study suggests that people pay more after receiving the offering when product value is high. Receiving the offering first makes the social exchange aspect of the transaction salient, which leads to buyers experiencing higher felt obligation toward sellers. However, the effect is mitigated when product value is low—when the social exchange is perceived as less substantive. In this case, the salience of the social exchange nature of the transaction after receiving the low-value offering highlights the fact that the exchange is not substantive, which leads to a lower felt obligation and lower payment.

We conducted a laboratory experiment in a large university in the United Kingdom where participants could pay any amount for an Amazon gift card with a specific value, as well as a field experiment at a restaurant in Nepal. Results from both experiments lent support to our predictions that consumers/participants pay more after receiving the offer versus before. The field experiment also provided preliminary evidence for the moderating role of product value; i.e., the effect of increased payment after receiving the product/service only holds true for items of higher value. We then tested our hypotheses with a large online study and found a reversal of the effect for low product value. In a final online study, this time in a charitable donation context, we again demonstrated the predicted payment decision timing effect for high product value as well as a mitigation of the effect for low product value.

Our findings offer two key takeaways for businesses that offer a voluntary payment element as well as for nonprofits, social enterprises, and charities where donations in exchange for a good or service are common.

Lessons for Chief Sales Officers

  • If the pay-what-you-want product is of high value, the seller should solicit pay-what-you-want payment after the product has been delivered to the consumer.
  • If the product is of sufficiently low value, the seller should solicit pay-what-you-want payment before the product has been delivered to the consumer.

For example, a community theater could employ a pay-what-you-want model when staging performances in an auditorium. The theater might opt to solicit payments before the performances at the entrance. However, if the community attendees tend to value the theater highly, it might be preferable to solicit payments from attendees after the performance.

Similarly, some eateries request that a payment be made before customers receive their order, and some restaurants request an upfront tip for large groups. Our findings suggest that if consumers perceive that the product is of high value (versus low value), it is more desirable to request a decision on a payment or a tip after (versus before) product delivery.

Read the full article.

From: Raghabendra P. KC, Vincent Mak, and Elie Ofek, “Before or After? The Effects of Payment Decision Timing in Pay-What-You-Want Contexts,” Journal of Marketing.

Go to the Journal of Marketing

Raghabendra P. KC is Assistant Professor of Marketing, Rollins College, USA.  

Vincent Mak is Professor of Marketing & Decision Sciences, University of Cambridge, UK.

Elie Ofek is Malcolm P. McNair Professor of Marketing, Harvard University, USA.

The owner of this website has made a commitment to accessibility and inclusion, please report any problems that you encounter using the contact form on this website. This site uses the WP ADA Compliance Check plugin to enhance accessibility.